PROJECTHousing Finance Reform Incubator

Patricia Mosser: Principles–and a solution–for GSE reform
Body

April 26, 2016

Replacing the housing securitization government-sponsored enterprises (GSEs)—Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac—is the biggest financial reform issue in the United States. It is a glaring gap compared with the extensive financial reforms in other parts of the financial system and seven-and-a-half years (and counting) of temporary government conservatorship. There have been many proposals to replace the activities of Fannie and Freddie, including a mutualized securitization utility that some of my colleagues and I outlined in two papers (Dechario et al. 2010; Mosser, Tracy, and Wright 2013). But more important than the details of our proposal to replace the GSEs are several key design principles—and a few hard-learned lessons—which need to guide reform.

Principles for reform

First, any replacement for Fannie and Freddie should be structured to reduce systemwide risk by insuring that those who make decisions about housing risk appropriately price and bear those risks. Because securitization is atomistic, this incentive alignment needs to happen across the entire housing securitization chain (i.e., borrowers, lenders, securitizers, investors, and the government). The entities responsible for covering losses must have a stake in which loans to securitize, the risk monitoring of loans, and the amount of credit protection (capital) needed. The failure of private-label securitization in the financial crisis was partly because of the failure to align the incentives of lenders, securitizers, and investors in this dimension. Any proposal to replace GSE-type securitization should not be structured with the same flaws that destroyed the private-label market. Instead, it must ensure that the securitization entity has skin in the game and can monitor, price, and enforce credit standards.

One implication of this principle is that there needs to be greater capacity to absorb losses for core mortgages consistent with capital requirements for other financial institutions. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac had skin in the game, just not enough. Another implication is that borrowers, lenders, and securitizers—all of whom influence lending decisions—should provide sufficient information to understand and monitor mortgage risks and have skin in the game. In other words, we need greater disclosure, meaningful household down payments (10 to 20 percent), close monitoring of credit quality, and risk retention.

Second, the housing finance system structure must be more robust and provide access to mortgage credit through the housing cycle. While this was an ostensible goal for the GSEs, they clearly could not do so without a government takeover. Moreover, this robustness cannot be achieved by merely spreading out or diversifying mortgage credit risk across many investors or financial companies. As the crisis proved, all boats rise and fall (or fail) together in a systemic real estate downturn.

Third, governments own the tail risk in housing finance. Across decades, countries and political regimes, and different types of financial systems, governments step in when house prices collapse and precipitate a financial crisis. While the form of government bailout can vary, there is no question that governments “reinsure” their housing finance systems in extremis (Laeven and Valencia 2010). Therefore, it is not credible (and not time-consistent policy) for the government to claim that it will not bail out the housing finance system. Moreover, if the government claims it will not provide a backstop, it is likely to provide incentives for more risk taking and leverage in the financial system through an unpriced implicit guarantee, making a housing-related boom-bust cycle more likely. Consistent with the first principle above, the government’s catastrophic reinsurance needs to be credible, explicit, and priced ex ante.

While governments must manage and price tail risk, they should not price and manage housing credit risk on a day-to-day basis. Setting standards and regulatory minimums is a government regulatory responsibility. Daily risk monitoring, repricing mortgage credit risk, and making monthly adjustments to issuer-specific fees are not. The history of government agencies and corporations has many examples of the private-sector actors "gaming” government entities, minimizing the costs and risks to the private sector and maximizing the risk taken by the government. In short, the government should price the (remote) tail risk it does face (already a difficult task) but not price normal mortgage credit risk.

Fourth, the current high degree of standardization of mortgages (particularly for fixed-rate loans) and the associated market structures (particularly the agency mortgage-backed securities, or MBS, market) are worth preserving if possible in a system consistent with the other design principles. Of course, the evolution of agency securitization reflects, in part, US homebuyers’ long-standing preference for long-term fixed-rate, fully amortizing loans with no prepayment penalties. Because such mortgages are a poor fit for most lender balance sheets, securitization and its associated market structures will be important for financing home mortgages.

Securitization of standardized mortgages has several benefits for borrowers, lenders, and investors. For borrowers, standardized fixed-rate mortgages provide some protection from interest rate fluctuations and simplify comparison shopping across competing lenders. Because of their long history in the United States, they are consumer protection products in that their properties and risks are well understood by borrowers. Moreover, one reason that the current agency MBS market is so much more efficient than private securitization markets is because of the relatively standardized, homogenous underwriting process and the straight-through processing embedded in the GSE securitization structure.

The large size and deep liquidity of the agency MBS market mean that investors in agency MBS require lower yields because the bonds can be sold with lower transactions cost and without a long, uncertain wait for a buyer. These lower yields contribute to lower borrowing costs for households and to less risk (and thus lower costs) to lenders making loans. Similarly, the current agency MBS market is a hedging vehicle not only for investors but also for lenders who hedge their pipeline of originated mortgages and interest rate locks offered to borrowers. In addition, lenders use the MBS markets to hedge risks of all types of mortgages—even those not intended or eligible for GSE-type securitization—which likely lowers the cost of those mortgages as well.

Last, standardized securitization is an infrastructure or a utility. It is a high-volume, low-margin business, as demonstrated by the relatively flat profitability of the Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac securitization business lines over time. In other words, standardized securitization has relatively large fixed costs and low marginal costs (the characteristics of a natural monopoly), which suggests that there will be one or very few firms. An important implication of this principle is that there are no efficiencies or benefits for conducting nonstandard securitizations within such a utility. Securitization of idiosyncratic or bespoke loans—such as those included in commercial real estate or multifamily residential MBS—is the opposite of a utility business. Margin costs are high. Every security—compositionally and structurally—is different, and most involve few individual loans, so there is no “law of large numbers” to diversify idiosyncratic risk. In short, any replacement for Fannie and Freddie should not include such securitizations.

Our proposal 

What do we advocate?

My coauthors and I previously proposed a mutualized financial market utility (FMU) to replace Fannie and Freddie securitization. The proposed FMU is a regulated private firm mutually owned by lenders, focused exclusively on securitization of standardized residential mortgages.1 The utility pools mortgages into pass-through MBS and provides a credit guarantee. It prices and manages credit risk of the mortgage pools it securitizes, subject to safety and soundness (capital) regulation, and it is required to buy catastrophic reinsurance from the government. It allows mortgage credit markets to function (or restart) even in times of market and economic distress by managing its capital waterfall on a vintage basis. Each vintage of mortgage risk (supporting multiple MBS) is separately capitalized and separately reinsured by the government, allowing for new capital (via a new vintage) to support origination of mortgage credit at the bottom of the cycle without additional government intervention.

How is this structure consistent with the principles above?

The mutualized ownership and loss-sharing structure in our proposed utility are designed to address the first principle of incentive alignment. Our FMU creates incentives to adopt and maintain common underwriting and securitization standards and, more importantly, for owners to closely monitor the credit quality of each other’s lending. Based on this monitoring, the utility can adjust pricing and guarantee fees of individual lender and member loans.

Appropriate incentive alignment also limits how much credit exposure the FMU can sell to other investors. This is important during housing booms, when it is easy for the utility to sell off all its credit risk. But without skin in the game, utility members would collectively ease credit standards, making the boom (and subsequent bust) worse. To avoid this outcome, the FMU must retain a portion of the mutual loss pool to insure appropriate risk management and ongoing monitoring of mortgage credit quality. Importantly, this also insures that the FMU has sufficient capital to fund new vintages, even in periods of market stress when external financing may not be available.

Moreover, characteristics of mutuals that may be seen as disadvantages for some types of financial companies are in fact advantages for our FMU proposal because they align the utility’s incentives with other actors in the securitization chain. Creating a utility with a narrow focus, an emphasis on cost control and efficiency, low risk taking, low return on equity, and low incentives for entrepreneurship and “mission creep”—all of which are characteristics of mutuals—is well aligned with the interests of owner/lenders and investors; with the government’s interest in insuring its backstop is sufficiently remote; and to offset monopolistic rent seeking. In practice, mutual ownership structures work well when they solve a principal agent problem—that is, when their business provides a service closely aligned to the needs of their owners and when owners are relatively homogeneous and knowledgeable (Hansmann 1999). All these characteristics fit our FMU.

The FMUs vintage structure and government reinsurance are designed to address robustness. Vintages compartmentalize credit loss pools and capital so that losses on specific vintages of MBS are covered by the capital available for that pool. Excess profits or capital (as defined by the regulator) from older vintages may be used as capital for newer vintages but not vice versa. To ensure robustness, “new” capital may not be shifted to cover past losses. Securitization can restart with a clean slate with new mortgages from lenders and fresh capital and guarantee fees that can be used only for current and future vintages.

Government catastrophic reinsurance is purchased by vintage, so the government does not reinsure idiosyncratic tail losses on individual MBSs but on extraordinarily large and widespread tail losses on an entire vintage. The government’s involvement naturally unwinds as the balance of the affected vintage pays down. Applying government reinsurance only after the FMU’s failure is not robust (because mortgage credit cannot be restarted) and risks repeating the conservatorship experience. Finally, by compartmentalizing risk (and tail risk insurance) in vintages, failure of the entire FMU is much less likely.

The FMU structure also reinforces secondary market liquidity and standardization of mortgages and is most likely to be used for fixed-rate loans. Our structure is consistent with recent efforts to create a single to-be-announced securities (TBA) market for delivery of mortgage pools and efforts by the Federal Housing Finance Agency on modernization and a new single securitization platform. In addition, mutualizing credit risk could facilitate creating larger and more diversified mortgage pools within the TBA market, which could improve liquidity, reduce market fragmentation, and lower mortgage costs.

Risks and Trade-offs

Like any proposal, our FMU is not without risks and challenges. Government reinsurance is notoriously hard to price. However, the previous price was zero (or negative because the government was subsidizing Fannie and Freddie’s risk-taking behavior across several dimensions), so even an imperfectly calculated positive price would be a step in the right direction.  Our proposal considers other key issues, such as retained portfolios (not allowed except for working out delinquencies), the amount of loss-absorbing capacity needed, and affordable housing programs (completely outside the FMU, perhaps funded by an addition to the guarantee fee).

Creating the mutual structure is challenging and reflects the large number of stakeholders in housing finance. From a governance perspective, the FMU would need to balance the needs of large and small members. This can be done several ways, including correspondent relationships akin to the arrangements used for other types of FMUs (e.g., clearinghouses). Even so, direct membership is likely to include small and large lenders, requiring a governance structure that encourages broad access for small lenders, but also risk-management oversight with sophisticated risk monitoring consistent with larger lenders.2 Creating a robust mutual structure will involve consultation with mortgage lenders, borrowers, and investors; new legislation; and importantly, a knowledgeable, sophisticated regulator with the power to write rules that can carefully balance the needs of the various stakeholders. Like many other proposals, ours likely needs a long lead time and creation of administrative “bridges” to new corporate structures.3

Notes

  1. Standardized mortgages need not necessarily be conforming, but those with common property, loan, and borrower characteristics. In practice and certainly at inception, most securitized mortgages are likely to be fixed rate.

  2. See Mosser, Tracy, and Wright (2013) for several proposed governance structures.

  3. Jim Millstein, “Jim Millstein: An Administrative Plan to Restructure and Reform the GSEs,” Urban Institute, last updated March 29, 2016, http://www.urban.org/policy-centers/housing-finance-policy-center/projects/housing-finance-reform-incubator/jim-millstein-administrative-plan-restructure-and-reform-gses.

References

Dechario, Toni, Patricia Mosser, Joseph Tracy, James Vickery, and Joshua Wright. 2010. “A Private Lender Cooperative Model for Residential Mortgage Finance.” In The American Mortgage System: Crisis and Reform, edited by Susan M. Wachter and Marvin M. Smith, 286–304. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press. (A preliminary version is available as a staff report from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.)

Hansmann, Henry. 1999. “Cooperative Firms in Theory and Practice.” Finnish Journal of Business Economics 4: 387–403. 

Laeven, Luc, and Fabian Valencia. 2010. Resolution of Banking Crises: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly. Working paper WP/10/146. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. 

Mosser, Patricia C., Joseph Tracy, and Joshua Wright. 2013. The Capital Structure and Governance of a Mortgage Securitization Utility. Staff Report 644. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 


Patricia C. Mosser is a senior research scholar and senior fellow at Columbia University’s School of International and Public Affairs and the director of a new initiative on central banking and financial policy.  Previously, Mosser was head of research and analysis for the Office of Financial Research at the US Department of the Treasury. She spent over 20 years at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York as a researcher and monetary policy practitioner. She was a senior manager at the bank’s open market desk, overseeing market analysis, foreign exchange operations, analysis of financial stability and reform, and monetary policy implementation, including many crisis-related facilities. Before that, she was an economist and manager in the New York Fed Research Department and  an assistant professor in the economics department at Columbia.  Mosser has written on monetary policy and financial stability topics, including crisis policy tools, the monetary transmission mechanism, and financial structure and reform. She has a BA from Wellesley College, an MSc with distinction from the London School of Economics, and a PhD from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. 

Image
A photo of Laurie Goodman. Dark hair, glasses, bright smile.
"It is time for an open-minded look at the housing finance system and what role, if any, today’s government-sponsored enterprises might play in the future."
Image
Tim Howard
"When invented narrative is replaced with verifiable fact, Fannie and Freddie cease to be a 'failed business model' that must be wound down and replaced; they instead become valuable resources that must be built upon and improved."
Image
A photo of Jim Millstein. White hair, slight smile, suit and tie.
"To address the conflict between their affordability mission and shareholder returns, the mortgage guaranty businesses should be subjected to utility-like regulation, with strict activity, leverage, and return on equity limitations."
Image
A photo of Alex Pollock. Slight smile, suit and tie.
"At the 10% Moment, Congress should declare the senior preferred stock fully retired, as in financial substance it will have been. Simultaneously, Congress should formally designate Fannie and Freddie as systematically important financial institutions.
Image
A photo of Mark Zandi. Slight smile, suit, brown hair.
"A group of us has put forward a reform proposal that addresses the system's structural problems and keeps what works."
Image
A photo of James Carr. Severe smile, suit, dark hair.
"The basic pillars of America’s housing finance system were enacted 80 years ago. Since then, major reconfigurations in our economy, demographic composition, and household locational preferences demand a bolder vision for housing finance in the 21st century."
Image
A photo of Andrew Davidson. Slgiht smile, greying hair, glasses.
"A realistic approach to GSE reform is to strip the GSEs down to the functions that promote standardization, liquidity, and access to credit, and adopt the best governance structures for those functions. This can be achieved in four steps: streamline, share risk, wrap, and mutualize."
Image
A photo of Mark Calabria. Slight smile, suit, dark hair, glasses.
“Mortgages, under any system, have to rest on someone’s balance sheet. Like water running downhill, the risk has flowed to the most leveraged sectors of our financial system. This is a recipe for instability.”
Image
A photo of Patricia Mosser. Dark hair, glasses, bright smile.
“The characteristics of mutuals that may be seen as disadvantages for some types of financial companies are in fact advantages for our financial market utility proposal because they align the utility’s incentives with other actors in the securitization chain.”
Image
A photo of Marc Morial. Big smile, suit, dark hair.
“In the aftermath of the Great Recession, the tragic loss of wealth, and the bailout of the big banks, our national government must continue to play a central role in the housing market to right previous wrongs, ensure access to all qualified borrowers, and keep the housing finance system afloat ...
Image
A photo of Laurie Goodman. Dark hair, glasses, bright smile.
"Between now and 2030, this country will face an unprecedented surge in rental housing demand. Already, rents are skyrocketing out of the reach for many families, especially in places with job opportunities. New multifamily housing construction is at its highest level since the 1986 Tax Refo...
Image
A photo of three individuals. All three are smiling, have suits, ties, and dark hair.
"There will be nuanced demands coming from the high concentration of household formation in African American, Asian, and Hispanic communities. Ginnie Mae 2.0 looks to be the safest way to build a sustainable platform to bring proven market stability to meet the needs of a materially changing demo...
Image
A photo of two individuals. Both are smiling, have suits, ties, and glasses.
“The most critical need for multifamily is simply that policymakers pay attention to it early and plan ahead.
Image
A photo of two individuals. Both are smiling, have suits, ties, and glasses.
We propose a spinoff of the multifamily business units of the GSEs and the formation of other new guarantors to increase access to affordable multifamily financing.
Image
A photo of two individuals. Both are smiling, have suits, and ties.
"Consensus exists that a reformed housing finance system must protect taxpayers, emphasize the private markets, support a broad variety of housing options and remain liquid throughout an economic cycle. Surprisingly, few recognize that a proven model already exists that meets those objectives-and...
Image
A photo of Jim Millstein outside. Dark hair, big smile, suit and tie, glasses.
"Mortgage finance reform discussions have failed to generate consensus assuring the widest possible access to sustainable mortgage credit at the lowest practical cost. We can resolve this impasse if we integrate all federal supports for mortgage finance into one cohesive whole."
Image
A photo of Pinto. White hair, glasses, slight smile, suit.
"Today’s government-centric housing finance system is an “economics free zone” indifferent to supply and demand. Composed of an alphabet soup of agencies, this system has fostered a massive liberalization of mortgage terms and provided countless trillions of dollars in lending. Yet housing has be...
Image
A photo of Taylor. White hair, suit.
"Much of the conversation on Capitol Hill and among policy thinkers has pushed affordability and access to the back burner. We need to bring it to the forefront of the conversation. The shape and quality of housing finance reform will have repercussions in every neighborhood and community and for...
Image
Mike Calhoun and Sarah Wolff
"Average price estimates obscure significant variation. To assess access and affordability, we need to look closely at differential prices, not just overall prices or prices for low–credit risk profiles."
Image
Rodrigo Lopez and Debra Still
"We believe that all housing needs, from the most directly-subsidized, affordable rental housing to the prime jumbo single-family lending market, lie along a single continuum. This housing continuum can be best served only by addressing single-family and multifamily, rental and homeownership, gov...
Image
Janet Murguía
"By 2020 half of all first-time homebuyers will be Latino. Without affordable access to credit for these prospective buyers, the housing market will decline, with harmful consequences on the larger economy."
Image
Jim Parrott
"Coming out of the crisis, there was thus almost universal agreement that we should reduce our reliance on this duopoly and shift more risk into a competitive private market."
Image
row of houses rendering
Research Areas Housing finance
Policy Centers Housing Finance Policy Center